Friday, October 31, 2014
5

Milton Friedman’s Magical Thinking

CAMBRIDGE – Next year will mark the 100th anniversary of Milton Friedman’s birth. Friedman was one of the twentieth century’s leading economists, a Nobel Prize winner who made notable contributions to monetary policy and consumption theory. But he will be remembered primarily as the visionary who provided the intellectual firepower for free-market enthusiasts during the second half of the century, and as the éminence grise behind the dramatic shift in the economic policies that took place after 1980.

At a time when skepticism about markets ran rampant, Friedman explained in clear, accessible language that private enterprise is the foundation of economic prosperity. All successful economies are built on thrift, hard work, and individual initiative. He railed against government regulations that encumber entrepreneurship and restrict markets. What Adam Smith was to the eighteenth century, Milton Friedman was to the twentieth.

As Friedman’s landmark television series “Free to Choose” was being broadcast in 1980, the world economy stood in the throes of a singular transformation. Inspired by Friedman’s ideas, Ronald Reagan, Margaret Thatcher, and many other government leaders began to dismantle the government restrictions and regulations that had been built up over the preceding decades.

China moved away from central planning and allowed markets to flourish – first in agricultural products and, eventually, in industrial goods. Latin America sharply reduced its trade barriers and privatized its state-owned firms. When the Berlin Wall fell in 1989, there was no doubt as to which direction the former command economies would take: towards free markets.

But Friedman also produced a less felicitous legacy. In his zeal to promote the power of markets, he drew too sharp a distinction between the market and the state. In effect, he presented government as the enemy of the market. He therefore blinded us to the evident reality that all successful economies are, in fact, mixed. Unfortunately, the world economy is still contending with that blindness in the aftermath of a financial crisis that resulted, in no small part, from letting financial markets run too free.

The Friedmanite perspective greatly underestimates the institutional prerequisites of markets. Let the government simply enforce property rights and contracts, and – presto! – markets can work their magic. In fact, the kind of markets that modern economies need are not self-creating, self-regulating, self-stabilizing, or self-legitimizing. Governments must invest in transport and communication networks; counteract asymmetric information, externalities, and unequal bargaining power; moderate financial panics and recessions; and respond to popular demands for safety nets and social insurance.

Markets are the essence of a market economy in the same sense that lemons are the essence of lemonade. Pure lemon juice is barely drinkable. To make good lemonade, you need to mix it with water and sugar. Of course, if you put too much water in the mix, you ruin the lemonade, just as too much government meddling can make markets dysfunctional. The trick is not to discard the water and the sugar, but to get the proportions right. Hong Kong, which Friedman held up as the exemplar of a free-market society, remains the exception to the mixed-economy rule – and even there the government has played a large role in providing land for housing.

The image most people will retain of Friedman is the smiling, diminutive, unassuming professor holding up a pencil in front of the cameras in “Free to Choose” to illustrate the power of markets. It took thousands of people all over the world to make this pencil, Friedman said – to mine the graphite, cut the wood, assemble the components, and market the final product. No single central authority coordinated their actions; that feat was accomplished by the magic of free markets and the price system.

More than 30 years later, there is an interesting coda to the pencil story (which in fact was based on an article by the economist Leonard E. Read). Today, most of the world’s pencils are produced in China – an economy that is a peculiar mix of private entrepreneurship and state direction.

A modern-day Friedman might want to ask how China has come to dominate the pencil industry, as it has so many others. There are better sources of graphite in Mexico and South Korea. Forest reserves are more plentiful in Indonesia and Brazil. Germany and the United States have better technology. China has lots of low-cost labor, but so does Bangladesh, Ethiopia, and many other populous low-income countries.

Undoubtedly, most of the credit belongs to the initiative and hard work Chinese entrepreneurs and laborers. But the present-day pencil story would be incomplete without citing China’s state-owned firms, which made the initial investments in technology and labor training; lax forest management policies, which kept wood artificially cheap; generous export subsidies; and government intervention in currency markets, which gives Chinese producers a significant cost advantage. China’s government has subsidized, protected, and goaded its firms to ensure rapid industrialization, thereby altering the global division of labor in its favor.

Friedman himself would have rued these government policies. Yet the tens of thousands of workers that pencil factories in China employ would most likely have remained poor farmers if the government had not given market forces a nudge to get the industry off the ground. Given China’s economic success, it is hard to deny the contribution made by the government’s industrialization policies.

Free-market enthusiasts’ place in the history of economic thought will remain secure. But thinkers like Friedman leave an ambiguous and puzzling legacy, because it is the interventionists who have succeeded in economic history, where it really matters.

Read more from our "Milton Friedman at 100" Focal Point.

Hide Comments Hide Comments Read Comments (5)

Please login or register to post a comment

  1. CommentedMichael Belzer

    An historical error here. Jimmy Carter was president in 1980. He brought Prof. Alfred Kahn from Cornell into the government as his "inflation czar" in 1977, and Fred Kahn turned the regulatory ship, introducing market liberalization in airlines, trucking, and railroads, for starters. Carter made the policy shift from regulated to liberal markets, but Reagan turned Kahn's deregulated markets into Friedman's and Baumol's ideological free markets, dismantling antitrust enforcement and the balance to which Dani Rodrik correctly refers.

  2. CommentedFrank O'Callaghan

    Milton Friedman’s views are well known. Even better known is the evidence of history. Free markets are inherently unstable. They are of benefit only to the powerful and do great social, environmental and economic harm to the rest of the world.

    Milton Friedman’s views have many supporters. The great dissent comes from the evidence. Repeated experiments with this worshiped theory have all ended with the same result; collapse, chaos and rescue by a society that must squander scarce resources to repair what should not have been destroyed. This is repeated every few decades.

  3. CommentedShane Beck

    The major difference between Adam Smith and Milton Friedman is that Adam Smith was always conscious that politics and economy were always inseparable while Milton Friedman focuses mainly upon the economy. Major economic events such as the European Monetary Union and China's admittance to the WTO (even though it is still heavily protectionist) had political foundations- the first was to prevent further war between European powers and the second was a belief that trade liberalization between China and the world would lead to greater democracy and a greater emphasis upon human rights (whether the growing middle class in China demands these rights remains to be seen.) Economics might tell you how to efficiently make the pie, but politics tells you how the pie will be divided....

  4. CommentedKen Presting

    It is a sad commentary on the state of economic discussion today that one makes a significant and welcome contribution by pointing out that all of our successful modern economies are mixtures of private free enterprise and public managament.

  5. CommentedSaruvash Adam

    Although it is good for China, one could question that if it would be the most beneficial outcome globally. An efficient outcome through the free market can offer an cheaper alternative. But good for China.

    Although the pencil story can be fought with a coda, it is generally true that free markets can provide a better outcome, even during a crisis. By trying to manage a crisis, one is providing insurance against a next crisis waiting to happen. It will always be bailed out, thinking of short term pain.

Featured