Saturday, September 20, 2014
4

Revisiting the Fed’s Crisis

BERKELEY – Reading through the just-released transcripts of the US Federal Reserve’s Federal Open Market Committee meetings in 2008, I found myself asking the same overarching question: What accounted for the FOMC’s blinkered mindset as crisis erupted all around it?

To be sure, some understood the true nature of the situation. As Jon Hilsenrath of the Wall Street Journal points out, William Dudley, then the executive vice president of the New York Fed’s Markets Group, presented staff research that sought, politely and compellingly, to turn the principals’ attention to where it needed to be focused. And FOMC members Janet Yellen, Donald Kohn, Eric Rosengren, and Frederic Mishkin, along with the Board of Governors in Washington clearly got the message. But the FOMC’s other eight members, and the rest of the senior staff? Not so much (albeit to greatly varying degrees).

As I read the transcripts, I recalled the long history dating back to 1825, and before, in which the uncontrolled failure of major banks triggered panic, a flight to quality, the collapse of asset prices, and depression. But there in the FOMC’s mid-September 2008 report, many members express self-congratulation for having found the strength to take the incomprehensible decision not to bail out Lehman Brothers.

I find myself thinking back to the winter of 2008, when I stole – and used as much as possible – an observation by the economist Larry Summers. In the aftermath of the housing bubble’s collapse and extraordinary losses in the derivatives market, Summers noted, banks would have to diminish leverage. While it would not matter much to any individual bank whether it did so by reducing its loan portfolio or by raising its capital, it mattered very much to the economy that the banks chose the second.

Even today, I cannot comprehend then-New York Fed President Timothy Geithner’s declaration in March 2008 that, “it is very hard to make the judgment now that the financial system as a whole or the banking system as a whole is undercapitalized.” Geithner’s view at the time was that “there is nothing more dangerous…than for people…to feed…concerns about…the basic core strength of the financial system.” Of course, we now know that indifference to such concerns turned out to be far more dangerous.

Likewise, I look at history and see that it is core inflation (which strips out volatile food and energy prices), not headline inflation, that matters for predicting future inflation (even future headline inflation). Then I read declarations like that by Dallas Federal Reserve President Richard Fisher, that dangerous inflationary pressure was building during the summer of 2008, and I find myself at a loss.

Some of the 2008-era mindset (most of it?) most likely stemmed from the fact that there are things that are very real and solid to monetary economists. We can see, touch, and feel how a financial-deleveraging cycle depresses aggregate demand. We know that this year’s change in an inertial price, such as wages, tells us a lot about next year’s wage changes, while this year’s change in a non-inertial price, such as oil, tells us next to nothing. And we know how herd behavior by investors means that a single salient bank failure can turn a financial mania into a panic, and then a crash.

But others do not see, touch, and feel these things. For non-economists, they are simply shadows on the walls of a cave.

That distinction was less relevant in the past. The Fed of old usually had a charismatic, autocratic, professional central banker at its head: Benjamin Strong, Marriner Eccles, William McChesney Martin, Paul Volcker, and Alan Greenspan. When it worked – which was not always true – the chair ruled the FOMC with an iron hand and with the near-lockstep voting support of the governors. The views of the other members – with their varying backgrounds in banking, regulation, and elsewhere – were of little or no concern.

But former Chairman Ben Bernanke’s FOMC was different. It was collegial, respectful, and consensus-oriented. As a result, there was a deep disconnect between Bernanke’s policy views, which followed from his analyses in the 1980’s and 1990’s of the Great Depression and Japan’s “lost decades,” and the FOMC’s failure in 2008 to sense what was coming and to guard against the major downside risks.

So I find myself wondering: What if those who understood the nature of the crisis and those who did not had been compelled to make their cases to Bernanke in private? If Bernanke had then said, “This is what we are going to do,” rather than seeking consensus – that is, if Bernanke’s Fed had been like the old Fed – would better monetary-policy decisions have been made in 2008?

Read more from "The Post-Bernanke World"

Hide Comments Hide Comments Read Comments (4)

Please login or register to post a comment

  1. CommentedPaul A. Myers

    Building a consensus in a group that includes individuals holding incorrect views necessarily leads to subtoptimal solutions. Possibly two opposing views should be presented and a vote taken with the majority being responsible for the results.

    But one suspects that the Federal Reserve law was set up so that one individual, the chairman, would be accountable for the results. The chairman should push for what is correct, by his or her lights.

  2. Commentedraul ramos

    25 february 2014 manila, ph

    economy in an intelligent view,

    “former fed chair ben bernanke planning a memoir”
    http://www.cnbc.com/id/101441774

    with all respect to you sir dr. ben s. bernanke,
    we love you sir. just to put my writings for the
    record. all my prayers is for you to succeed in
    your decisions and the judgement that you’ve
    made on that historical, fateful day. again since
    year 2008 i had written this so many times that
    if america chooses the right, the correct directions,
    everybody will benefit but once it made a slight
    mistake, a wrong decisions, trust me it will be fatal.
    all of us will surely and definitely suffer. thanks’

    my facebook account:

    thegreatdepression.part2@yahoo.com

    kindly please take care and God bless . . . . . . . raul

  3. CommentedJoan Miro

    Gee, I don't know, what if a long line of conservatives, from Reagan to Obama, did not worship at the altar of the free market? What if there had not been a slow and steady dismantling of all the New Deal era regulations that centered on a conservative, stable, and well regulated banking system? What if complex derivatives, those "financial weapons of mass destruction," had been carefully regulated (or prohibited) rather than being allowed to function in a netherworld? And what if the Senate vetoed any appointment of a Treasury Secretary who was a former head of Goldman Sachs or foreign currency trader for Goldman Sachs or a NY Fed Chief who was willfully asleep at the wheel to allow the Goldman Sachses of the world to run amok?

    Then maybe we wouldn't need an iron-fisted Fed chief.

  4. CommentedProcyon Mukherjee

    Hindsight sometimes blissfully ignores what the immediacy of a crisis cannot, the over-arching need to arrest and sequester a cascade like phenomenon when the tipping point was triggered cannot be so simply wished off as a failure to act with an iron hand instead of working with a consensus.

    The bursting of a bubble, the size of which has not been seen by anyone in the past and the asymmetric knee-jerk reaction likewise thereafter (post the burst) wasn’t entirely predictable; to pin the hopes that a proactive action by the Fed (including saving Lehman) could have yielded a less harmful effect on the economy needs to be weighed against the further deepening of leverage against the back-drop of withering collaterals, while the rising hint of moral hazard would have dented all hopes of tapered risk-taking as Fed would have moved from a “lender of last resort” to a “shoulder of all risks”.

Featured