Tuesday, July 22, 2014
Exit from comment view mode. Click to hide this space
6

Misleading Indicators

BELLEVUE, WASHINGTON – “If you can’t measure it, you can’t manage it.” That is the wisdom behind metrics like gross domestic product and other aggregate indicators that signal the health of national economies around the world. Policymakers and planners have used these numbers for decades to help them understand how to guide domestic economic growth.

But reliance on GDP and other traditional indicators may be sabotaging a keenly sought goal: the development of thriving innovation economies. Today, some vital parts of the information-technology sector barely register in the national accounts. While GDP measures the market value of all goods and services produced within a country, many stars of the digital age (think Wikipedia, Facebook, Twitter, Mozilla, Netscape, and so on) produce no goods and provide free services.

These same star players also tend to undercut the productivity of traditional businesses. Free navigation apps have shrunk sales for Garmin, the GPS pioneer that was once one of the fastest-growing companies in the United States. Skype is killing the international phone call “one minute at a time.”

These developments point to the need for new growth metrics that recognize new kinds of enterprise. And, because these metrics concern innovation, they should be forward-looking as well. Policymakers need to understand how to establish, manage, and thus measure the conditions that encourage innovators to flock to a region and forge a prosperous future there. Innovation metrics must capture the value of new ideas years before those ideas become profitable in traditionally measured ways.

The need for such metrics is especially urgent in the developing world. Emerging economies commonly use foreign direct investment (FDI) as a yardstick to measure progress. That metric makes sense in the early stages of development: poor economies need foreign capital to build factories, train workers, and put money in the pockets of ordinary citizens.

But foreign investment most often goes to low-risk, low-margin projects: iron foundries, cement plants, and so forth. Innovation, by contrast, is a high-risk, high-reward effort. Even big multinationals do not put a lot of money into a new idea at first. Tomorrow’s most disruptive innovation may have no effect on FDI or GDP today.

Thus, for countries like China, India, and Brazil that are trying to jump-start their domestic innovation cultures, FDI targets actually prevent government planners from reaching out to the people and companies that are most likely to take creative approaches to problems.

So what does valuable innovation look like, in terms of macroeconomic data, years before it gives rise to the next Google, Bayer, Porsche, or Alibaba? What numbers best characterize a thriving innovation ecosystem in its birth stages?

We already know some of the essential ingredients. They include top-level talent, serial entrepreneurs with good track records, start-ups backed by reputable capital, and breakthrough products protected by intellectual-property rights. Analysts at my company recently investigated whether these ingredients could be quantified. Our preliminary results suggest that they can.

For example, we learned that five of today’s most successful start-ups in the information-technology sector had two attributes in common by the end of their third year in business: they had filed more than one patent and been funded by more than one top venture-capital firm. In subsequent years, these five companies’ cumulative revenue was six times higher than that of start-ups chosen at random.

Economists could extend such analyses to develop a set of key performance indicators for young innovation economies. Governments could then use these innovation metrics to identify start-ups, talent, and products with the strongest potential for future success. This approach could be applied to any high-tech incubator project – within or beyond the developing world – that currently measures success only in dollars.

Of course, such metrics would merely improve the odds of succeeding, not point to a sure thing. Innovation economies will always require investments in a multitude of prospects to produce the few big winners that will ultimately anchor the mature ecosystem. But even a modest improvement in odds will deliver outsize results if it means landing two Apples or Samsungs rather than one – or none.

Changing how we think about economic value will not be easy. Yet countries where GDP has been flagging – an ever-increasing cohort – might welcome new metrics that can show signs of real progress. And there is a growing awareness among policymakers and planners that virtual assets like creative talent and entrepreneurial skill make up an increasing portion of a country’s wealth.

The US Bureau of Economic Analysis acknowledged as much last summer when it changed the definition of GDP to represent better the contributions of intellectual property and research and development to productivity and economic vitality. Broader efforts to reform GDP, including initiatives sponsored by the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development and the European Commission, seek to encompass sustainability, living standards, and other important aspects of a country’s wellbeing. Groups like the Institute for New Economic Thinking are championing the study of innovation economics to provide data and analyses for these efforts.

As former US Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke noted in a 2011 speech, “We will be more likely to promote innovative activity if we are able to measure it more effectively and document its role in economic growth.”

In fact, metrics that help countries drive innovation could change our very understanding of economic growth. Governments want them, economies need them, and the global community will benefit from them. It is time for macroeconomics to measure up to the ambitions of twenty-first-century innovators.

Read more from the "The Innovation Revolution"

Exit from comment view mode. Click to hide this space
Hide Comments Hide Comments Read Comments (6)

Please login or register to post a comment

  1. CommentedJason Gower

    This article seems to be all over the place. I think the bigger question about GDP is the methodology of calculating it (difficulty measuring substitution effects, quality, etc., etc.) not its usefulness. GDP serves a very useful purpose.

    On the other hand, yes, innovation is a crucial indicator that is difficult to measure but could provide policymakers with an important indicator if new, clever ways of measuring it are devised. This is more of a "balance sheet" item to be used in analyzing a nation though. Similar to a corporation we look at physical and intangible assets, we can look at the capital stock and intangibles like innovation as the assets of a nation. The example citing Wiki, Facebook, etc.) was also confusing considering the author included companies that absolutely produce services to the tune of a triple digit market cap in the case of fb. What is that example meant to say? That these "free" services in the case of say, Wikipedia, through their cannibalism of existing corporations, should somehow be translated into a GDP deflator of some sort?

    All in all I think GDP is one of the most useful economic indicators you will find (when you dig into its components) and indicators measuring innovation would also serve a very useful purpose.

  2. CommentedVenu Madhav

    It might be prudent to have a metric to understand Gross Efficiency Increase (GEI) on a per annum basis. The reasoning for this is, the more output that we can get within a week/ month/ year utilizing all of these snazzy, disruptive killer apps not justifies the utility of the app obviously but also has a net-net impact on the living standards of workforce, like for example, work-from-home enabling technologies has a good impact on reducing vehicular traffic in congested cities and other health benefits added.

  3. CommentedMatt Stillerman

    This article seems a bit self-serving. Intellectual Ventures is a non-practicing entity or NPE. That means that they don't actually produce anything. They just sue people who do produce stuff. Oh, and those lawsuits involve lots of legal services on both sides that count towards GDP.

    Are we really better off with more lawsuits? Well, it does combat homelessness among the legal profession. But wouldn't we be better off if these same people were paid similar amounts of money to do something less harmful? Just saying.

  4. CommentedLeo Arouet

    Por un momento pensé que no nos daría los factores de medición, pero nos ha dado dos elementos: las patentes y las firmas centrales de capital de riesgo.
    Aunque esto es un comienzo, es un avance para identificar a las startups del futuro. Los gobiernos pueden alentar la innovación, destinando recursos para nuevas empresas y proyectos productivos ya sean informáticos o industriales.

  5. CommentedS. Bait

    The indicators are not misleading. It is just the planners were driving by looking at the rear view mirror, assuming what gave them good GDP growth in the past will continue to provide good growth in the future, instead of finding the area that provide good potential growth in the future, understand their own strengths and weaknesses, and plot a course to improve the growth picture in the future.

Featured