Thursday, October 23, 2014
5

The Meaning of Cyprus

BRUSSELS – The root of the problem in Cyprus is well known. Its two major banks had attracted huge deposits from abroad, largely from Russia, and presumably mostly from individuals who wished to escape scrutiny at home or elsewhere. The proceeds were then invested in Greek government bonds and loans to Greek companies. When Greece imploded, the investments turned sour, and the Cypriot banks that had engaged in this strategy became insolvent.

Given this situation, the logical choice for the country should have been clear: if the government wanted to survive, foreign depositors must bear part of the losses. It is thus difficult to understand why the Cypriot government was at first so reluctant to inflict any losses on depositors.

But the solution that was eventually agreed makes sense: the country’s two largest banks are effectively resolved. Their bad assets will be separated and wound down over time. Neither the Cypriot government nor European taxpayers will put any additional funds into these banks. The losses that remain after the bad assets have been disposed of will thus have to be borne by the banks’ uninsured creditors, which in this case means those with deposits of more than €100,000 ($130,000).

Although Cyprus is too small to matter for global financial markets, the crisis there could turn out to be an important precedent guiding how European policymakers deal with future banking problems. In particular, it could affect current plans for a “banking union,” which needs three elements: a single supervisor, a common resolution authority, and a credible system of deposit insurance. The Cyprus crisis holds important lessons on all three counts.

First, the crisis has underscored the need for a single supervisor that is not captured by local interests. The European Central Bank would never have allowed Cypriot banks to attract huge deposits by paying above-market interest rates, and then to put all of their eggs in one basket (Greece). This was a high-risk strategy without a safety net.

Second, while there is still some discussion about how to create a common resolution mechanism for eurozone banks, events have shown that the ECB already de facto fills this role. No bank in difficulties can survive if the ECB does not grant or renew emergency liquidity assistance.

This accumulation of power in the hands of a completely independent institution is, of course, not ideal from the standpoint of democratic accountability. But this should serve as an additional incentive for the eurozone’s member states to agree to the creation of a genuine common resolution authority with enough funding to resolve even larger banks in an orderly way.

Finally, the revolt of Cyprus’s small savers highlighted the need for a credible system of deposit insurance. The EU directive that stipulates the protection of bank deposits up to €100,000 does not provide a European guarantee; it only requires member states to create a deposit-insurance system at the national level.

In reality, however, there has been a widespread misperception that somehow “Europe” protects small depositors. Yet a common deposit-insurance system had, at least so far, not even been under discussion, because the issue was not perceived as a live problem. Cyprus has shattered this complacency. Leaving deposit insurance exclusively at the national level is no longer an option.

Cyprus also holds a more general lesson: Given the extreme reaction of financial markets to the collapse of Lehman Brothers in 2008, it had become axiomatic among European policymakers that no bank should be allowed to become insolvent. But financial markets reacted calmly to the news that, for the first time, even depositors in a bank in the European Union will lose part of their money (and this was noted with glee in Berlin and elsewhere in northern Europe).

The key lesson for European policymakers is thus that it is possible to “bail in” a bank’s creditors. This has not been officially admitted, but Eurogroup President Jeroen Dijsselbloem, the Dutch finance minister, expressed it clearly, saying that, after Cyprus, Europe should become more courageous in bailing in bank creditors.

This realization – that the European taxpayer does not have to save every troubled bank – might have a very beneficial effect, because Germany’s resistance to a banking union is motivated by the fear that German taxpayers would be forced to underwrite indirectly the losses of banks in the distressed countries of the eurozone periphery. This fear may now ease.

The crisis in Cyprus represents an extreme and special case in many respects. But the way that the problem arose, and the solution that was finally adopted, is likely to have very important consequences for the way that Europe will address its banking problems.

Hide Comments Hide Comments Read Comments (5)

Please login or register to post a comment

  1. CommentedKonstantinos Sofokleous

    It wouldn't have been difficult to understand the hesitation, if you knew that all Cypriot politicians (most of them lawyers) have firms that provide services to the large foreign depositors.

  2. CommentedMarco Cattaneo

    A European banking union would solve nothing. The eurozone cannot survive unless monetary autonomy is restored on a country-by-country basis. http://bastaconleurocrisi.blogspot.it/2013/02/tax-credit-certificates-to-start-up.html

  3. CommentedP. Foofootos

    The data say that 23% of deposits were Russian (Barclay's). of those, 40% are estimated to be money of dubious origin, which means the estimates are that in total 9.2% of deposits are of Russian dubious origin. If you check data from Financial Secrecy Index or FATF-GAFI, you'll see that even as a ratio, Cyprus is small potatoes when it comes to foreign black capital (with countries like Switzerland, Luxembourg, and even Germany having the top places on the list). BTW the articles referencing data instead of Russian gangster stereotypes are virtually nonexistant.

    Now, the "Logical choice" would be for the government to cover the guaranteed deposits in their own currency, which granted would mean comparative with the current (albeit temporary in this case) substantial losses in the beginning, but better future prospects. Cyprus entered the euro in 2004, has an economy based exclusively on commerce and foreign capital for the last 2500(!) years, and before the dreaded euro had surpluses, small inflation, strong currency and small debt. It doesn't really seem logical to change an economic model working for thousands of years because countries with higher taxes consider tax heavens unfair competition, or frown on the service sector and think only people in manufacturing are working. To each his own (taxes).

  4. CommentedSimon van Norden

    The "glee" in Northern Europe may be due to the advantage this gives to banking systems in low-debt nations. Depositors in the periphery should understand that deposit insurance underwritten by debt-constrained national governments is literally incredible under this new EU policy. The logical response is capital flight (particularly for large commercial accounts) from high- to low-debt nations, as well as more use of repo-based bank borrowing. The former should be expected to worsen regional economic tensions in the EU. The latter was the key trigger of systemic instability in US banking in 2008.

  5. CommentedSimon van Norden

    What is the "Logic" that makes this choice clear?
    - govt. survival is best aided by finding external aid (e.g. ECB etc.) to contribute
    - forcing losses on banking depositors invites capital flight and a potential banking panic.
    - there seems to be an attempt here to suggest that depositors were somehow "unsavory", so forcing them to pay for their bankers' mistakes is "just"

Featured