Wednesday, November 26, 2014
5

The French Death Rattle

PARIS – Moody’s announcement in November that it had downgraded France’s sovereign-credit rating by one notch from its AAA rating prompted one blogger to poke fun at rating agencies’ tendency either to get things completely wrong or to recognize suddenly a crisis that had long been staring them in the face. The blogger joked, “If this recognition by a rating agency that France has problems is an example of the first failing, a recovery must have begun; if it is an example of the second failing, the country faces a dire reckoning.”

French President François Hollande’s government claims to have awoken to the threat. In a recent interview, Finance Minister Pierre Moscovici likened the measures being undertaken to reduce the country’s debt burden and restore competitiveness to a “Copernican revolution...because these choices were not clear for a French government or for a center-left government.”

As proof of this new realism, the government has been trumpeting its response to the set of policy recommendations that an expert panel led by the business executive Louis Gallois presented two weeks before the downgrade. The response is centered on a payroll-tax cut, which will be offset by spending cuts and a higher value-added tax.

In the run-up to the downgrade, an analyst at Moody’s said that the decision would be based largely on whether the government heeded the Gallois report’s call for a “competitiveness shock” to France’s economy. The downgrade thus suggests that Moody’s considered the government’s response insufficient.

In fact, this negative verdict barely scratches the surface of France’s predicament. The full picture emerges only after examining the motivations behind the government’s inadequate response.

The underlying explanation lies in the culture and prejudices of France’s governing elite, the so-called grands commis formed by the National Civil Service School of which Hollande – like virtually all of his predecessors, except Nicolas Sarkozy – is an alumnus. In this cloistered world, a prosperous and just society requires a state-directed economy.

This dedication to dirigisme has spawned among the ruling elite a sense of entitlement and hostility to business. Indeed, for France’s political leaders, business amounts to a zero-sum competition to capture a higher share of total value added for owners and managers, at the expense of labor.

Criticism of this anti-business approach is usually dismissed in France as “ultra-liberal” flailing against the “social model” that the French nation has embraced. But the example set by Scandinavian countries, which combine a generous welfare state with pro-business policies and traditions, repudiates such claims.

The main difference between the failing French model and the more successful Scandinavian approach lies not in welfare “outputs” (many public services in France, such as the health-care system, remain among the best in the world), but in how they are financed. The Scandinavian social compact rests on the understanding that citizens must pay high taxes in exchange for public services.

While French public spending – which stood at 56% of GDP in 2011 – is at or above Scandinavian levels, French households pay lower tax rates on consumption and personal income. The gap is bridged by a mixture of deficit spending and high taxation on employment.

Relentless government borrowing and high payroll taxes (employer-paid social security) have long sustained citizens’ illusion that they are getting something for nothing, while perpetuating successive governments’ misconception that taxing business is a painless way of financing welfare and public services. But it is increasingly apparent that this approach has undermined public finances and competitiveness – and that households end up picking up the tab. (In fact, chronically high unemployment has meant that they have been doing so for years.) Now, citizens are facing higher taxes and cuts to public services.

Defenders of the French system quibble over labor-cost statistics in their efforts to prove that France is not so different from its main European trading partners. But the facts of the last decade – including a significant loss of export-market share and a 5%-of-GDP deterioration in the current-account balance – paint a different picture.

Moreover, this line of defense misses the point. The burden of payroll taxes, together with overweening labor-market regulation, stifles entrepreneurship. If Hollande’s tax hikes – on income (including a temporary 75% tax rate for the country’s wealthiest households), dividends, capital gains, and capital assets – are not enough to deter entrepreneurs, the cost of hiring workers and the difficulty of firing them remain powerful disincentives.

Far from signifying a pro-business shift, Hollande’s government’s response to the Gallois report reflects the French elite’s enduring interventionist mentality. Instead of implementing deep and permanent cuts in payroll taxes on businesses, the government will give companies a €20 billion ($26 billion) income-tax credit over the next two years. And, with companies required to apply the rebated cash to investment and job creation, the government has portrayed the measure as a cut in taxes on labor that will boost employment. But a temporary tax break cannot change incentives.

Furthermore, companies will not receive the cash until 2014-2015, owing to the complexity of France’s tax administration. And, when they do get it, the state cannot possibly know that reinvesting in the same enterprise will be more beneficial than, say, paying out dividends that shareholders could then use to finance a new venture.

Once again, French lawmakers are acting on the conviction that they know better than market participants. Apart from promises to reduce employment regulation, all of the new measures boil down to officials directing state money and subsidies to companies and projects of their choosing.

So the death rattle of the French economic model continues. What remains to be seen is how the end will come. And, whether it comes in the form of a capital strike by foreign bondholders, or of domestic labor strikes and wider social and political unrest, France’s leaders remain entirely unprepared for the inevitable.

  • Contact us to secure rights

     

  • Hide Comments Hide Comments Read Comments (5)

    Please login or register to post a comment

    1. CommentedBasle Jean-Luc

      Agree with the author's analysis.
      One comment on the French government tax credit: companies will invest and hire workers if and only if they are confident they can sell their products – an unlikely prospect in today’s environment. The companies which will avail themselves of the program are those companies involved in growth sectdors which would have invested in the next two years in any case. The program will have a windfall effect for these few lucky companies.

    2. Commentedjean-louis salvignol

      Chris Mahoney puts the point where it hurts. If there is an etatist French model that transcends political labels, this model is completely incompatible with the rules governing the EZ. These rules were negotiated in their time by the former socialist power. One remembers Maastricht, Amsterdam, Nice. The question is to know how Mr. Hollande with his omnipotent socialist power goes to get France out of the deadlock it is blocked, thanks to himself and his comrades.

    3. CommentedJules Pierre

      And so the death rattle of the ultraliberal model continues. There is no such thing as trickle down or market efficiency (this article rests on both). One that does not acknowledge the flaws of his own thinking has no legitimacy to ask others to do so. Ultraliberal economists are just as stubborn as french politicians.

    4. Portrait of Christopher T. Mahoney

      CommentedChristopher T. Mahoney

      There is no doubt that France has designed its economy to thwart market forces, limit wealth-creation, and deliver subpar growth. However, the current deficiency in aggregate demand is not France's fault. France surrendered its monetary sovereignty to Frankfurt thirteen years ago. Frankfurt believes that 2% nominal GDP growth is quite acceptable. Unfortunately, socialism government can't run on 2% nominal growth without resorting to large fiscal deficits. The challenge for France is not to figure out how to raise taxes and cut spending. The challenge is to find a way to force the ECB to target something better than deflation and depression. Otherwise, even a Thatcherite policy will fail. France needs 5-6% nominal growth to avoid Spanish-style bankruptcy.

    5. CommentedPaul de La Motte

      Nice deterministic one sided argument. The case in favour of the Scandinavian model has already been discussed a myriad of times and needless to repeat, again, that it is neither applicable nor desired in greater scale economies such as in the UK or France. Interesting to note how some remain in total deny when it comes to the reality of market failure. A dirigist state is probably what is best needed in times of crisis, and I would even go further to add that this is definitely one of the best strengths of the French model.

    Featured